
Raymond Richman - Jesse Richman - Howard Richman
Richmans' Trade and Taxes Blog
Does trading away our future buy the US friends?
Jesse Richman, 5/7/2015
Writing on May 3 in the Washington Post, the often thoughtful and perceptive Robert J. Samuelson made a fall-back argument for the Trans Pacific Partnership: it's good politics, even if the economics are lousy. The fall back is a weak position, however. Is it truly good politics in the long run to pursue imbalanced trade policies that undermine U.S. power?
Samuelson notes that the economic benefits of the deal would be extremely modest: "Still, plausible economic gains from expanded trade seem modest. By 2025, the incomes of the 12 countries could increase by 0.9 percent, according to a revised estimate by a study for the Peterson Institute." He appears to assume that these will be divided equally though if current patterns hold and U.S. trade deficits with partnership nations grow substantially, the benefits will likely not flow to the U.S. much at all.
But he argues that US trade policy isn't about economics: it's about politics. "Still, the pursuit of political ends by economic means remains at the core of U.S. trade policy."
Defeat of TPP, he argues, would mark the end of the era of U.S. trade liberalization.
"A Trans-Pacific Partnership failure — because countries don’t agree or Congress kills the final result — could produce a historic watershed. Present U.S. trade policy dates to congressional passage of the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1934, which authorized the president to negotiate tariff cuts with other countries. (Before that, U.S. trade policy was highly protectionist.) A TPP rejection could mean the end of an era.
“It would be taken as a signal that the United States wasn’t able to maintain the consensus and commitment that we’ve had since [the mid-1930s] for trade liberalization,” says University of Maryland political scientist I.M. Destler.
...
"We seek to reassure nations that we’re still a Pacific power and that our proposal represents a useful framework to govern the region’s trade. A collapse would leave a vacuum that China would most likely fill. Through its own trade agreements, China might fashion a system that gives its exports preferential access to foreign markets, while securing guaranteed supplies of raw materials (oil, grains, minerals). That’s not in our interests.
Samuelson concludes:
"So when opponents criticize the Trans-Pacific Partnership, they need to answer a simple question: compared to what?"
The answer to the "compared to what" question needs to begin by noting that the fact that we feel the pressing need to reassure Asian allies that we are "still a Pacific power" through a weak trade deal that endorses continued mercantilism at the expense of American workers has almost everything to do with the failures of our trade policy.
The rising economic and political challenge posed by China has a great deal to do with the enormous trade deficits the United States has run with China for decades. The decline of U.S. industrial capability and by association U.S. power is what calls into question our continued role as a Pacific power, and the trade deficits have contributed mightily to that decline. Doubling down on a policy that has contributed so much to U.S. decline hardly seems to be a good plan. Compared to what? How about starting off by balancing trade with China.
A policy of balanced trade would force trading partners to reciprocally open their markets to U.S. goods and services if they want access to the U.S. market. It would much more closely embody the reciprocal spirit of the 1934 reciprocal tariff act than the current strategy of tolerating imbalanced trade in order to buy friends. Imbalanced trade has already worked so well at buying the friendship of China that we are now called on to
Samuelson's reference to the reciprocal tariff law of 1934 is misleading. Reciprocal free trade is on the whole a good idea. But the "reciprocal" policy began to metastasize when the advantages negotiated reciprocally with one trading partner began to be extended to other trading partners who had made no similar reciprocal concessions. This has put the U.S. in it's current weak negotiating position. We have few tariffs or other trade barriers to remove, our trading partners have many more. And consequently they have little motive to make real concessions.
|